This comment piece was first published on OpenDemocracy,
under the title: ‘It is time for a post-drug war Marshall Plan’, 1 August 2012
If prohibition was a genuine protection racket, at least we
would be protected from harm. But it isn’t. It is much worse than that. It is
effectively an “endangerment racket”, argues Danny Kushlick
Fifty years ago almost every United Nations member state
signed up to support a global prohibition on the non-medical use of certain
drugs. Ever since, citizens all over the world have repeatedly voted for
governments that proclaim the virtues of fighting a “war on drugs”. Through
taxes we pay governments to enforce drug laws to protect us, our children, our
communities and our countries from the all too real harms of drug misuse.
However, the regime of prohibition (the criminalisation of
production, supply and use) has been applied only to certain drugs. It has
rarely been applied to tobacco and alcohol. But who does this prohibition
protect?
In a classic protection racket, a racketeer threatens damage
to a business, or harm to an individual, unless the victim pays the racketeer
“protection” money. The 1961 UN
Single Convention on drugs, to which the UK is a signatory, frames its
approach in terms of a concern for the “health and welfare of mankind” and a
desire to “combat” the “serious evil” of “addiction to narcotic drugs”. It then
places an obligation on signatories to put in place a blanket prohibition (and
thereby eliminate use and eradicate supply) in order to protect us from this
“evil”.
The threat, as articulated, is that if we do not support the
prohibition, the “evil” will take over and we will no longer be “protected”
from addiction. But the global prohibition – the “war on drugs” – has
singularly failed to stop people using drugs. The reality is that worldwide
there are up to 300 million users. All the evidence shows that the level of law
enforcement has little or no correlation with levels of drug misuse.
Not only has law failed to regulate drugs misuse, like
alcohol prohibition, the war on drugs has gifted the multi-billion pound trade
to drug-trafficking organisations and unregulated dealers, who are genuinely
dangerous to all of us, our children and our communities. In 2008, The UN Office on Drugs and Crime conceded that the
“drug control system” (a euphemism for prohibition) itself fuels the $320
billion a year criminal trade, describing it as one of five major “unintended
consequences”. The recently published Alternative
World Drug Report gives an even more comprehensive exposition of the harms
caused by the war on drugs.
Governments use this “unintended consequence” - the creation
of the second largest money earner for organised crime globally - as a further
pretext to demand more “protection” money. However, this second payment, now
apparently spent on fighting organised crime, does nothing to stop drug
trafficking organisations. In fact, it serves as a price support mechanism,
turning simple agricultural products into commodities literally worth more than
their weight in gold. An understanding of basic economics tells us that
squeezing the supply of any trade that has a high and resilient level of demand will serve only to
raise the price (notwithstanding the fact that prices are further hiked by
virtue of the risk undertaken throughout the supply chain). And so a
self-perpetuating vicious circle is created, whereby control of the market by
unregulated suppliers is used to justify continuation or escalation of the war.
These two “rackets” (the one built upon the other) have not
only failed to protect communities and children, but have also brought entire
nation-states to their knees. Prohibition has turned Guinea Bissau, for
example, from a fragile state to a narco-state within months of the cocaine
trade crossing its borders.
Prohibition has also brought the law into disrepute around
the world, as millions break an unenforceable law mastly using whatever drugs they
want, whilst the vast criminal profits are used to corrupt officials at all
levels. Prohibition has made the drugs trade as dirty and dangerous as it could
possibly be; unregulated dealers sell adulterated drugs to minors and violent
criminals control much of the trade, and more than 50,000 Mexicans have died in
drug-related violence since 2006. Year after year the Afghan poppy crop supplies
the majority of the raw material for the manufacture of illegal heroin.
If prohibition was a genuine protection racket, at least we
would be protected from harm. But it isn’t. It is much worse than that. It is
effectively an “endangerment racket”. The first payment we make creates
plentiful money-making opportunities for organised crime. The second payment
provides the budgets for those given the task of “fighting organised crime” –
FBI, CIA DEA, SOCA and many others around the world. The second payment of
“endangerment money” distracts us from the fallout from the first racket and
further serves to perpetuate the overarching prohibitionist regime.
However, there is good news. Governments are not organised
crime groups. We can stop paying “endangerment money” any time we like, by
voting for an individual or party that is seeking alternatives to global
prohibition, and the endangerment racket that accompanies it.
We can stop governments spending our money on a regime that
ultimately endangers those who are most vulnerable and at risk, and press them
to reassign the vast sums involved to a “post-drug war Marshall Plan”. Around
the world we are seeing the beginning of more pragmatic approaches to legalisation and regulation.
As citizens we have a choice. We can use our vote for peace – or for war.
2 comments:
which party is currently advocating an end to the torture and discrimination that some drug users suffer from our government?
Post a Comment